首页 乘数的巫术

乘数的巫术

举报
开通vip

乘数的巫术 -�- Economists’ Voice www.bepress.com/ev February, 2009© The Berkeley Electronic Press Voodoo Multipliers RoBERT J. BaRRo B ack in the 1980s, many commentators ridiculed as “voo- doo economics” the extreme supply-side view that across-the- board cuts in i...

乘数的巫术
-�- Economists’ Voice www.bepress.com/ev February, 2009© The Berkeley Electronic Press Voodoo Multipliers RoBERT J. BaRRo B ack in the 1980s, many commentators ridiculed as “voo- doo economics” the extreme supply-side view that across-the- board cuts in income-tax rates might raise overall tax revenues. Now we have instead the extreme demand-side view that the multiplier effect of government spending on output is greater than one (Team Obama is reportedly using a number around 1.5). To think about this assumed multiplier, suppose first that it took on the lower value 1.0. In this case, an increase by one unit in government purchases and, thereby, in the aggregate demand for goods would lead to an increase by one unit in real gross domestic product (GDP). Thus, the added public goods are essentially free to society. If the government buys another airplane or bridge, the econo- my’s total output expands by enough to create the airplane or bridge without requiring a cut in anyone’s consumption or investment. The explanation for this magic is that idle resources—unemployed labor and capital— are put to work to produce the added goods and services. If there is a social cost, it is only that people who used to be unemployed have less leisure because they are working. If the multiplier is greater than 1.0, as apparently assumed by Team Obama, the process is even more wonderful. In this case, real GDP rises by more than the increase in government purchases. Thus, in addition to the free airplane or bridge, we also have more goods and services left over to raise private consumption or investment. In this scenario, the government spending is a good idea even if the bridge goes to nowhere or if government employees are just uselessly filling holes. This free lunch would make Charles Ponzi proud. If the deal is genuine, why stop with only $1 trillion or so of added government purchases? So, where is the flaw in the argument? The theory (a simple Keynesian macroeconomic model) implicitly assumes that the govern- ment is better than the private market at mar- shaling idle resources to produce useful stuff. Unemployed labor and capital can be utilized at essentially zero social cost, but the private market is somehow unable to figure any of Robert J. Barro is the Paul M. Warburg Professor of Economics at Harvard University, a senior fellow of the Hoover Institution of Stanford University, and a research associate of the National Bureau of Economic Research. -�- Economists’ Voice www.bepress.com/ev February, 2009 this out. Implicitly, there is something wrong with the price system. Keynes thought that the problem lay with wages and prices that were stuck at excessive levels. But this prob- lem could be readily solved by expansionary monetary policy, enough of which will mean that wages and prices do not have to fall. So, something deeper must be involved—but economists have not convincingly identified market failures, such as incomplete informa- tion or moral-hazard problems, that generate multipliers above one. A much more plausible starting point is a multiplier of zero. In this case, the real GDP is given, and a rise in government purchases requires an equal fall in the total of other parts of GDP—consumption, investment, and net exports. In other words, the social cost of one unit of additional government purchases is one. This approach is the one usually applied to cost-benefit analyses of public projects. In particular, the value of the project (counting, say, the whole flow of future benefits from a bridge or a road) has to justify the cost of the public outlay. I think this perspective, not the supposed macroeconomic benefits from fiscal stimulus, is the right one to apply to the many new and expanded government programs that we are likely to see this year and next. Aside from theory, what is true about multipliers in the data? Because it is not easy to separate movements in government pur- chases from overall business fluctuations, the best evidence comes from large changes in military purchases that are driven by shifts in war and peace. A particularly good experi- ment is the massive expansion of U.S. defense expenditures during World War II. This case works well because the United States from 1941 to 1945 did not suffer from the mas- sive destruction of property and life that led to large declines in real GDP in many other countries during WWII. In any event, the usual Keynesian view is that the WWII fiscal expansion provided the stimulus that finally got the U.S. economy out of the Great Depres- sion. Thus, I think that most macroeconomists would regard this case as a fair one for seeing whether a large multiplier ever exists. I have estimated (in my book Macroeco- nomics, A Modern Approach) that World War II raised U.S. real defense expenditures by $540 billion (1996 dollars) per year at the peak in 1943–44, amounting to 44% of trend real GDP. I also estimated that the war raised real GDP above trend by $430 billion per year in 1943–44. Thus, the multiplier was 0.8 (430/540). The other way to put this is that the war lowered components of GDP aside from military purchases. The main declines were in private investment, non-military parts of gov- ernment purchases, and net exports—personal consumer expenditure changed little. We can consider similarly three other U.S. wartime experiences—World War I, the Korean War, and the Vietnam War—although the added defense expenditures were much smaller in comparison to GDP than that for WWII. When I combined the evidence for all four wars, I got an overall estimate of the mul- tiplier of 0.8, the same value as before. (This similarity is not so surprising because WWII gets a lot of weight due to its particularly large change in government purchases when expressed as a ratio to GDP.) In an earlier study in the Journal of Political Economy, I got a similar regression-based estimate for the multiplier effect on real GDP from tem- porary defense purchases—for a sample from 1942 to 1978, the coefficient was 0.71, with a standard error of 0.06. -�- Economists’ Voice www.bepress.com/ev February, 2009 There are reasons to believe that the war-based multiplier of around 0.8 substantially overstates the multiplier for peacetime government purchases. For one thing, the temporary nature of much of mili- tary spending during wars means that con- sumer demand would not fall a lot. In con- trast, an increase in non-war spending—which historically has been mostly permanent— would tend to reduce consumer demand substantially through a negative income ef- fect. Second, the use of the military draft in wartime has a direct, coercive effect on total employment. Third, the U.S. economy was al- ready growing rapidly after 1933 (aside from the 1938 recession), and it is probably unfair to ascribe all of the rapid GDP growth from 1941 to 1945 to the added military outlays. Another point is that the added labor during the two world wars was very large, and much of this expansion cannot be viewed as merely putting idle labor to work. For example, the dramatic rise in female labor during WWII likely had a sizable social cost. When I attempted to estimate directly the multiplier associated with peacetime government purchases, I got a number that was statistically insignificantly different from zero. In the regression-based results from my 1981 Journal of Political Economy paper, for the sample from 1942 to 1978, the esti- mate was 0.14 with a standard error of 0.51. Thus, the regression did not pin down the non-war multiplier very well. As we all know, we are in the middle of what will likely be the worst U.S. economic contrac- tion since the 1930s. In this context and from the history of the Great Depression, I can un- derstand various attempts to prop up the finan- cial system. These efforts, akin to avoiding bank runs in prior periods, recognize that the social consequences of credit-market decisions extend well beyond the individuals and businesses making the decisions. That is, externalities are likely to be important in the financial sector. But, in terms of fiscal-stimulus proposals, it would be sad if the best that Team Obama can offer is an unvarnished version of Keynes’s General Theory, 1936. The financial crisis and possible depression—which I take very seri- ously—do not invalidate everything we have learned about macroeconomics since 1936. In designing effective policy responses, much more focus should be on incentives for people and businesses to invest, produce, and work. On the tax side of fiscal stimulus, we should avoid programs that throw money at people and emphasize instead reductions in marginal income-tax rates—especially where these rates are already high and fall on capital income. We should keep in mind the struc- ture of rate-cutting programs that worked: Kennedy-Johnson 1963–64, Reagan 1981–83 and 1986, and Bush 2003. At the present moment, the full elimination of the federal corporate income tax would be brilliant. (In the long run, the best way to raise more real tax revenue—for example, to pay for health- care and public retirement programs—is likely to involve a value-added tax. However, I hesi- tate to recommend this efficient form of taxa- tion because its presence makes it too easy for government to grow.) Going back to the spending side, my main point is that we should not use the cover of fiscal stimulus to undertake massive public- works programs that do not pass muster from the perspective of cost-benefit analysis. (And, by the way, “shovel-ready project” is probably the silliest term I have ever heard in a discus- sion of macroeconomic policy.) Just as in the -�- Economists’ Voice www.bepress.com/ev February, 2009 1980s, when extreme supply-side views on tax cuts were unjustified, it is wrong now to think that added government spending is free. Letters commenting on this piece or others may be submitted at http://www.bepress.com/cgi/ submit.cgi?context=ev. references and further reading Barro, Robert (2008) Macroeconomics, A Modern Approach, Cincinnati, South-Western College Pub. Barro, Robert (1981) “Output Effects of Govern- ment Purchases,” Journal of Political Economy, 89(6):1115. acknowledgment An earlier version of this article appeared in the Wall Street Journal. Material republished with per- mission.
本文档为【乘数的巫术】,请使用软件OFFICE或WPS软件打开。作品中的文字与图均可以修改和编辑, 图片更改请在作品中右键图片并更换,文字修改请直接点击文字进行修改,也可以新增和删除文档中的内容。
该文档来自用户分享,如有侵权行为请发邮件ishare@vip.sina.com联系网站客服,我们会及时删除。
[版权声明] 本站所有资料为用户分享产生,若发现您的权利被侵害,请联系客服邮件isharekefu@iask.cn,我们尽快处理。
本作品所展示的图片、画像、字体、音乐的版权可能需版权方额外授权,请谨慎使用。
网站提供的党政主题相关内容(国旗、国徽、党徽..)目的在于配合国家政策宣传,仅限个人学习分享使用,禁止用于任何广告和商用目的。
下载需要: 免费 已有0 人下载
最新资料
资料动态
专题动态
is_902270
暂无简介~
格式:pdf
大小:118KB
软件:PDF阅读器
页数:4
分类:金融/投资/证券
上传时间:2011-05-18
浏览量:16